SAN
DIEGO — THE big story in Silicon Valley these days is a class-action
lawsuit alleging that several major tech companies, including Google and
Apple, agreed not to try to hire away one another’s employees — thereby
hindering workers from seeking out better-paying jobs.
But
do-not-hire agreements are not the only way that corporations are
taking control of their employees’ intellectual capital. From Thomas
Edison to Steve Jobs, the individual inventor is a hero in our popular
imagination. But increasingly it is corporations, not people, who own
inventions.
This
ownership runs deeper than inventions and artistic works, extending to
skills, ideas and professional ties — tacit knowledge and social
relations that cannot be subject to patent or copyright under the
traditional scope of intellectual property, but which corporations lay
claim to at increasing rates through employment agreements.
In
these agreements, companies demand that employees, from those in
low-level manufacturing positions to design engineers and creative
workers, sign away all their innovations, and the knowledge they will
acquire during the course of employment, and refrain from competing with
their employer post-employment, whether that means taking a new job
with a competitor or starting their own company.
While
some states place some limit on such agreements in their labor codes,
for the most part, employers can demand ownership over almost all
aspects of our cognitive ability — from their products to their uses —
long after we have moved on to different endeavors.
Moreover,
unlike other high-patenting countries like Germany, Finland, Japan and
China, which require businesses to pay the inventor who assigns an
invention to them, American intellectual property law lacks any
requirements that employers compensate employees for the fruits of their
creative labors above their regular salary.
Companies
have been making more expansive claims to their employees’ mental work
for over a decade. In 2004 a court in Texas ordered a former Alcatel
employee to give his former employer a software algorithm — which
existed entirely in his mind. The idea, which he was still working on
and was still too abstract and incomplete to be a patentable invention,
was nevertheless deemed the property of Alcatel, forcing the ex-employee
to turn over the algorithm in the months after he was fired.
With
more corporations demanding that employees pre-assign their
intellectual property, there has been a steady decrease in
inventor-owned patents. A couple of decades ago, individuals owned about
25 percent of all patents. Now, individuals own barely 10 percent; the
rest are corporate-owned.
And
this disparity is about to become even more pronounced. In 2013 the
America Invents Act went into effect, shifting our patent system from a
first-to-invent to a first-to-file rule. That will aid corporations and
harm individual inventors, who will usually lack the funding to speed up
filing.
A
world where what is fair and what is law diverge so markedly raises a
number of important moral, legal and economic questions, the most basic
and important of which is: How does a reality in which we own so little
of what we create affect our drive to make something new and original?
To answer this question, the marketing professor On Amir and I
researched how ownership over our skills and creative ventures affects
our motivation to perform. In a study
published this year in the Harvard Business Review, we reported on a
series of behavioral experiments in which we asked over a thousand
participants to perform various tasks and solve problems.
We
divided the subjects into two groups. We told one set that they were
free to later perform similar work for other “employers” in the virtual
workplace of our experiment. We asked the others to sign over ownership
of their skills to, and sign noncompete agreements with, their current
“employers.”
All
of the participants were assured that they would be paid for the tasks
they performed in the experiment. But the effects of giving up future
control over one’s own skills and products of the mind were significant.
When we asked participants to relinquish ownership of their skills,
they became less focused on the problem, spent less time on the task and
made twice as many errors as the unconstrained group.
These
effects were mitigated when our subjects found the tasks particularly
interesting in and of themselves, but even then, the constraints we
imposed on their human capital suppressed their motivation to perform
well.
Certainly,
we are not driven solely by ownership. To be human is to create, and we
thrive when we use our talents in productive ways. But our research
shows that no one can sustain creative energies on passion alone.
This
loss of creative fire is not only costly for individuals. In a world in
which economic growth depends on innovation, we simply cannot afford
such limitations on creativity.
No comments:
Post a Comment