Rob Urie
RINF Alternative News
RINF Alternative News
Part of the challenge of addressing political
economy is the different realms that economic and philosophical
discourse exist in. Western (capitalist) economics can be informed by
history but it can’t accommodate it. This can be seen in response to
French economist Thomas Piketty’s new book ‘Capital in the Twenty First
Century.’ The effort, nay contrived ‘necessity,’ of quantifying income
distribution across history, as Piketty has done, places it at the
center of what could in different terms leave it as bit player, as
artifact rather than base discursive fact. This isn’t to argue that
income distribution isn’t ‘important.’ It is to argue that there are
other, possibly more illuminating, ways of getting to issues of economic
cum political asymmetries and their role in social outcomes. By staying
within the anti-historical historiography of ‘income’ and its
quantification across time a limited history is presented as the
addition of ‘facts’ when it could alternatively be understood to be a
detraction that leaves the base premises of capitalist theory largely
untouched by design. This probably won’t make much sense to those raised
in the Western economic tradition so I will spend some time below
trying to relate the thesis across different modes of discourse. This
effort bears some relation to the Cambridge Capital Controversy in the
sense that the terms exist in what appear to be irreconcilable realms.
For instance, the Western storyline of the
IMF’s (International Monetary Fund’s) role in Ukraine is of providing
financial ‘assistance’ to a nation in need. The point has been made that
IMF loans will simply replace Ukraine’s debt to Russia with debt to it,
‘the West.’ That is, ‘Western’ funds will be used to pay for energy
sold to Ukraine by Russia at a subsidized price in exchange for Ukraine
implementing ‘austerity’ policies at the behest of the IMF. When
considered in conjunction with CIA
and EU machinations to assert political control over Ukraine the
intersection of geopolitics and economics is exposed. Debt is being used
as a weapon to exert economic control over Ukraine under the guise of
providing financial assistance. ‘Privatization’ of nominally public
assets is a central goal of IMF imposed austerity. Lest the point be
taken too narrowly, since the 1980s U.S. investment banks have used debt
to wrest control of Western corporations from ‘stakeholders’ in order
to loot worker’s resources like pension funds and wage agreements
leaving behind de facto ‘private’ austerity. And in the 1970s and 1980s
‘money center’ banks in New York made loans to ‘nations’ across South America
at the behest of the US government with the ultimate result being
neo-liberal ‘reforms’ forced onto ‘debtor countries’ and citizenries who
saw little to no benefit from this debt being forced to repay it. In
the terms associated with ‘income inequality,’ is asymmetrical income
distribution cause or effect? And in what way is it dissociable from
three centuries of Western imperial history? Where precisely does the
‘state of nature’ exist that renders reduction to quantum of
interest—‘income,’ addition?
When it comes to ‘discussing’ income
distribution, particularly in the US, a tightly circumscribed storyline
is near instantaneously brought forward where variants on anomaly,
institutional particularity and ‘nature’ are intermingled to assert a
patina of gentility to facts of history better described as barbarous.
Current Western geopolitical machinations in / on Iran date to the decision by US and British ‘intelligence’ agencies in 1953 to overthrow the democratically elected President of Iran in order to secure Iranian oil for what is today British Petroleum. British Petroleum is presently the major supplier of oil and oil products to the US military. Mid-twentieth century US incursions into South and Central America
and Cuba at the behest of the United Fruit Company, today re-branded
‘Chiquita,’ were similarly undertaken in Honduras, Nicaragua and El
Salvador by US President Ronald Reagan in the 1980s to protect Coca Cola
bottlers from nationalization (Nicaragua) and to ‘free’ regional labor
to sew underwear for Wal-Mart and Target for pennies an hour. Regular US
incursions into Haiti since the 1940s left Democrat President Bill
Clinton with the brilliant-lite, but instinctually neo-imperialist,
insight that Haitians could likewise sew underwear for rich Americans
for pennies an hour. (See Haitian debt to France for additional
insight). The Mexican migration northward to the US in the 1990s and
early 2000s coincided with NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement)
destroying indigenous agriculture in Mexico by flooding it with
subsidized industrial corn from the US. Of relevance: economic relations
with basis in history are only claimed ‘natural’ by emptying the term
of meaning. A history of income inequality that poses concentrated
income and wealth as potential cause of economic dysfunction,
‘patrimonial capitalism,’ reifies the Western economic conceit that an
anti-historical ‘state of nature’ from whence ‘inequality’ arises is
either plausible or even vaguely theoretically coherent.
On a different path American economist-historian Robert Heilbroner argued in 1966 in ‘The Limits of American Capitalism’ that
a residual plutocracy (my term) and corporate executives earning ten
times the average wage of ‘their’ workers ran the American economy and
US foreign policy. Today the ratio of executive to average worker
compensation is 341:1. This isn’t to infer / require either that
Heilbroner was ‘right’ or that greater concentration of income is
without effect. But there was no ‘clean’ dissociation of economic
outcomes from expression of political power either then or now. As
uncomfortable and cluttered as this may be to discussion of income
distribution, the very premise of ‘income inequality’ is that income
equality would in some way resolve the barbarous genesis of Western
‘wealth.’ The point in raising Heilbroner isn’t of relative versus
absolute wealth distribution but of the historically indissociable role
of capitalist ‘wealth’ to its broader social facts and in the acts that
place it at the center of interest. To the extent Heilbroner was ‘right’
the quantity of income, either relative or absolute, is artifact of
capitalist (anti) social relations. Capitalism is an approach to ‘the
world,’ not simply to its economic ‘aspect.’ By framing income
inequality as cause and leaving ‘its’ genesis in imperial history as
‘unrelated,’ or even marginally related through coincidence, the problem
raised— the creation, persistence and self-perpetuating character of
social asymmetries and their related facts, is left unarticulated and
therefore necessarily unresolved.
The conspicuous concentration of ‘wealth’ in
recent decades has led to the term ‘income inequality’ being thrown
around as if it has meaning outside of a much broader set of premises
about the social relations that Western economics purports to address.
The very idea of ‘equality’ behind the phrase is a restatement of the
social role of money— ‘income,’ the quantum that is the theorized basis
for the possibility of equivalence behind ‘inequality.’ Phrased
differently, of what coherence is ‘equality’ without a place for it to
reside beyond the particular (the concept is wholly metaphysical). Money
is the social creation that reifies this metaphysical space,
which poses thought as ‘fact’ and puts it back as personal possession.
‘Income’ as money receipts is the metric, the thing that answers its own
question: by what measure does this inequality have meaning?—by its
own. You and I form the ‘we’ of theorized in / equivalence but I am not
you and you are not me. This ‘we’ is social ‘object’ as are money and
income, the difference being that money is reified social relation, the
‘object’ of social division into ‘yours’ and ‘mine.’ To invert the
high-capitalist metaphor, or rather Marx’s critique of it, the
billionaire left alone on a desert island with her money has but piles
of paper or digital entries— the fishes and the palm trees exist outside
the ‘we’ that give money the only meaning / ‘value’ it has, social
meaning.
Framed differently, under what set of
premises should the social allocation of money— ‘income,’ be ‘equal?’
The answer implied in use of the phrase ‘income inequality’ is that
there is basis. Capitalism is in theory premised on social allocation
according to economic contribution— unless contribution is under some
measure ‘equal’ then unequal distribution is the ‘correct’ outcome of
capitalism. Ironically, ‘homogenous’ labor is in neo-classical
(capitalist revival) economics the ‘equivalent’ labor used to legitimate
outsourcing, unequal pay for ‘equivalent’ work, through relocating
economic production to areas with lower wages. Assuming similar
capacities a worker in a factory in China or a McDonalds in Paris (sorry
France) will produce the same physical quantity of product as workers
in Des Moines or Pittsburgh, but the difference in pay that they receive
is used to claim that the ‘value’ that each produces is a function of
the wages paid. And the wages paid are used to argue that workers are
paid according to the ‘value’ that each produces. The argument is wholly
circular, but so is the whole of capitalist economics. To be clear,
this isn’t a gratuitous slam; it is a function of the basis of
capitalist economics in Cartesian metaphysics. The starting point for
this economics is ‘first principles’ that are dogma— they can’t be
refuted without discarding Western economics in its entirety. The
narrower point is the nexus of income and labor, or income and
‘capital,’ as both determinant of and measure of ‘their’ ‘product.’
Income is the explanation of ‘value,’ which in turn is the alleged basis
of income (disparities) in capitalist economics.
This brings us to Piketty’s r>g, the rate
of return on capital (wealth) is greater than the rate of economic
growth. The basic argument is that in recent history, as well as in
select earlier periods, wealth has accumulated faster than its
‘material’ base in goods and services produced. If left unchecked the
logical (mathematical) consequence is that concentrated wealth will
continue to concentrate until a few people own all economic production.
To relate the issue to the Cambridge Capital Controversy, one problem
with this formulation is that both ‘r’ and ‘g’ are placed in the
dimension of ‘r’ through the use of money as the metric of
commensurability. A ‘twenty-thousand dollar car’ is a car regardless of
the monetary value assigned to it— it is ‘its’ own fact related to all
of the ‘facts’ that went into its production regardless of their
monetary value. The reason why this might matter is that there are the
facts of economic production— the making of things and the things used
to make things, ‘technology,’
and there are social claims on this economic production. These are two
separate things. The contemporary capitalist claim that ‘technology’,
or more broadly ‘capital’ in its neo-classical understanding, is the
cause of income inequality is circular in the sense that the assignment
of ‘value’ produced by it is both input and output, it is a base
assertion that is put forward as fact of ‘nature.’ Without the
imposition of money as metric of commensurability (metaphysical
‘equivalence’) Marx’s labor theory of value is more coherent than the
capitalist explanation leaving technology
in the realm of embedded labor rather than as ‘capital’ posed in
(confused) opposition to it. The Cambridge Controversy was in part over
the issue of logical circularity but the larger issue was / is of the
imposition of capitalist metaphysics through rate of profit that simply
assumes that its imposition ‘settles’ issues that in fact result from
the premises being irreconcilable. With r>g Piketty asserts that a
‘twenty-thousand dollar car’ is a ‘twenty-thousand dollar car’ as if the
claim had basis in nature rather than in social relations. (Marx’s
labor theory of value is more coherent than capitalist theories because
of its basis in / tie to the act of production. Capitalist theories are
circular because they are metaphysical— they derive from logical first
principles that not even capitalist economists care to defend as
plausible. The two theories are wholly irreconcilable because they
proceed from different dimensions).
The concentration of social claims on social
production, ‘wealth,’ poses particular arrangement of circumstance as
indubitable fact. Mountain top removal to mine for coal assumes
commensurability between the price paid for the land, the cost of
removing the mountaintop and mining the coal and the price paid for the
coal in ‘exchange.’ Left unaccounted for are the social and
environmental costs of mining for and burning coal. There is no
commensurability, no crossing of dimensions, that makes money and
monetary ‘value’ equivalent to what was destroyed. There may be some
residual accounted for in capitalist theory, some ‘externality,’ but
there is no ‘equivalence’ that leaves mountaintops undestroyed and air
unpolluted. Likewise, the ‘income’ of ‘income inequality’ is abstracted
from its social facts, from its broader genesis in historical relations
and pre-existing social asymmetries, and put back as object of wholly
implausible equivalence. It is this base idea of equivalence, of the
very possibility of equivalence, that renders the idea of ‘income in /
equality’ fundamentally incoherent. Through this idea of equivalence the
dodge is to keep the facts of Western capitalism: imperial history, the
persistence, in fact the creation, of asymmetrical social relations and
social and environmental dysfunction increasingly in evidence, at the
level of a counting game. To be clear, this isn’t to argue against
income redistribution. It is to broaden the fight, and a fight it is, to
argue that capitalist theories of economic production are fundamentally
incoherent and that theoretical incoherence is closely related to the
accumulating social and environmental dysfunction that are its facts.
Phrased differently, arguing over income restates / legitimates its
role as claim on social resources when it is the facts of capitalist
economic production that are of greater consequence.
The ‘pragmatic’ rationale for addressing
income inequality appears to be to ‘improve’ capitalism. This is the
apparent point behind the distinction of productive and unproductive
wealth / capital. But either there exists a benevolent ‘nature’ that
distributes income justly or there isn’t. This phrasing may seem quaint,
but what then is the reason for wanting to improve capitalism if this
isn’t the case? And wanting to improve capitalism bears no necessary
relation to alleviating the social and environmental pathologies it
creates. An argument is even being put forward that
‘solving’ global warming can leave the capitalist ‘growth’ imperative
intact. ‘Externalities,’ e.g. global warming, are costs of capitalist
production that others are forced to bear. If capitalists benefit from
forcing others to bear their costs of production (income inequality
anyone? Anyone?) why would they forego this ‘benefit’ without being
forced to? The central hindrance to addressing global warming has been
Western governments held captive by particular economic interests who
benefit from not solving environmental issues. Wall Street wants to not
solve the problem by trading pollution rights. Big oil
wants to not solve the problem to maintain its role in the fossil fuel
economy. If it is possible to resolve the social and environmental
consequences of capitalism while leaving it intact, where is the
evidence? Efforts made in the 1970s to regulate industrial pollution
were abandoned under the argument that ‘we all’ benefit from capitalist
production. The redistribution schemes of the New Deal were abandoned
under the quaint theoretical premise of ‘disincentives’ at the heart of
capitalist theory. In other words, the problems were known and
understood before they were mis-re-forgotten. Claims that these issues
are solvable within the existing order are clearly contradicted by
history.
Rob Urie is an artist and political economist. His book Zen Economics will be published by CounterPunch / AK Press shortly.
No comments:
Post a Comment